12 Apr 2025

picking up cheap shoes in front of a steamroller

Here’s another privacy paradox for people who collect them.

  • On the web, the average personalized ad is probably better than the average non-personalized ad. (The same ad campaigns that have a decent budget for ad creative also have a budget for targeting data.)

  • But users who block personalized ads, or avoid personalization by using privacy tools and settings, are, on average, better off than users who get personalized ads.

There’s an expression in finance: Picking Up Nickels In Front Of A Steam Roller. For some kinds of investing decisions, the investor is more likely to make a small gain than to lose money in each individual trade. But the total expected return over time is negative, because a large loss is an unlikely outcome of each trade. The decision to accept personalized ads or try to avoid them might be a similar bet.

For example, a typical positive outcome of getting personalized ads might be getting better shoes, cheaper. There’s a company in China that is working the personalized ad system really well. Instead of paying for high production value ads featuring high-profile athletes in the USA, they’re just doing the incremental data-driven marketing thing. Make shoes, experiment with the personalized ad system, watch the numbers, reinvest in both shoe improvements and improvements to the personalized ads. For customers, the shoe company represents the best-case scenario for turning on the personalized ads. You get a pair of shoes from China for $40 that are about as good as the $150 shoes from China that you would get from a a big-name brand. (The shoes might even be made by the same people out of the same materials.) I don’t need to link to the company, just turn on personalized ads and if you want the shoes they’ll find you.

That example might be an outlier on the win-win side, though. On average, personalized (behaviorally targeted) ads are likely to be associated with lower quality vendors and higher product prices compared to competing alternatives found among search results. (Mustri et al.) but let’s pretend for a minute and say you figured out how to get targeted in the best possible way and come out on the winning side. That’s pretty sweet—personalized ads save you more than a hundred bucks on shoes, right?

Here comes the steamroller, though.

In recent news, Baltimore sues 2 sportsbooks over alleged exploitative practices. Some people are likely to develop a gambling problem, and if you don’t know in advance whether or not you’re one of them, should you have the personalized ads turned on? You stand to lose a lot more than you would have gained by getting the cheap shoes or other miscellaneous stuff. It is possible that machine learning on the advertising or recommended content side could know more about you than you do, and the negative outcomes from falling for an online elder fraud scheme tend to be much larger than the positive outcomes from selecting the best of competing legitimate products.

The personalized advertising system can facilitate both win-win offers like the good shoes from an unknown brand or win-lose offers like those from sports betting apps that use predatory practices. The presence of both win-win and win-lose offers in the market is a fact that keeps getting oversimplified away by personalized advertising’s advocates in academia. In practice, ad personalization gives an advantage to deceptive sellers. Another good example comes from the b2b side: malware in search ads personalized to an employee portal or SaaS application. From the CIO point of view, are you better off having employees get better-personalized search ads at work, or better off blocking a security incident before it starts?

People’s reactions to personalization are worth watching, and reflect more widely held understanding of how information works in markets than personalized ad fandom does. The fact that Google may have used this data to conduct focused ad campaigns targeted back to you was disclosed as if it was a security issue, which makes sense. Greg Knauss writes, Blue Shield says that no bad actor was involved, but is that really true? Shouldn’t a product that, apparently by default, takes literally anything it can—privacy be damned—and tosses it into the old ad-o-matic not be considered the output of a bad actor? Many people (but not everybody) consider being targeted for a personalized ad as a threat in itself. More: personalization risks

06 Apr 2025

converting PDFs for Tesseract

There are two kinds of PDFs. Some have real embedded text that you can select in a PDF reader, and some are just images.

The second kind is what I sometimes get in response to a CCPA/CPRA Right to Know. Some companies, for whatever reason, want to make it harder to do automated processing of multiple RtKs. This should make privacy researchers more likely to look at them, because what are they hiding and they must be up to something.

But the PDF still needs to get run through some kind of OCR. Tesseract OCR has been giving me pretty good results, but it needs to be fed images, not PDFs.

So I have been feeding the PDFs to pdf2image—in Python code, and then passing the images to Tesseract. But it turns out that Tessaract works a lot better with higher resolution images, and the default for pdf2image is 200 DPI. So I’m gettting a lot more accurate OCR by making the images oversized with the dpi named parameter:

pages = pdf2image.convert_from_bytes(blob, dpi=600)

I might tweak this and try 300 DPI, or also try passing grayscale=True to preserve more information. Some other approaches to try next, if I need them.

Anyway, Meta (Facebook) made some of their info easy to parse (in JSON format) and got some of us to do research on them. Some of the other interesting companies, though, are going to be those who put in the time to obfuscate their responses to RtKs.

28 Mar 2025

More money and better stuff for people in the UK

Some good news last week: Meta settles UK ‘right to object to ad-tracking’ lawsuit by agreeing not to track plaintiff. Tanya O’Carroll, in the UK, has settled a case with Meta, and the company must stop using her data for ad targeting when she uses its services. It’s not a change for everyone, though, since the settlement is just for one person. O’Carroll said she is unable to disclose full details of the tracking-free access Meta will be providing in her case but she confirmed that she will not have to pay Meta.

The Open Rights Group now has a Meta opt-out page that anyone in the UK can use to do an opt out under the UK GDPR.

If you use any Meta products – Facebook, Instagram, Meta Quest or VR, Threads or WhatsApp – you can use our tool to request that they no longer collect or process your data for advertising. This is known as your right to object, which is enshrined in data protection law. Meta had tried to get around GDPR, but by settling Tanya’s case they have admitted that they need to give their users this right.

If you’re in the UK, you can either use the form on the site, or use the mailto link to open up a new regular email from your own account pre-populated with the opt out text. This is a win not just because it could mean less money for a transnational criminal organization and more money staying in the UK, but also because it’s going to mean better products and services for the people who do it.

Opt outs are one layer in the onion.

  • Don’t do a surveilled activity

  • Block the transfer of tracking data

  • Generate tracking data that is hard to link to you

  • Set an opt out while doing the surveilled activity

  • Send an opt out or Right to Delete after doing the surveilled activity

Having access to this new tool doesn’t mean not to do the others. Even if I could figure out how to use the Meta apps in a way that’s totally safe for me, it’s still a win to switch away because it helps build network effects for the alternatives and more safety for other people. So even if you do this opt out, it’s also a good idea to do the other effective privacy tips.

How this gets you more money and better stuff

Turning off the personalized ads is a bigger deal than it looks like. The arguments from advertising personalization fans don’t reflect the best research on the subject. Ad personalization systems, especially on Facebook, are designed to give some hard-to-overcome advantages to deceptive advertisers. Any limitations to personalization look like a big win, shopping-wise. In one study, turning on an Apple privacy setting reduced reported fraud losses by 4.7%.

The personalization of ads on Facebook helps vendors of crappy, misrepresented goods match their products to the shoppers who are most likely to fall for their bullshit. Yes, you can follow the advice in articles like Don’t Get Scammed! Tips For Spotting AI-Generated Fake Products Online on Bellingcat, but it’s a time-saver and an extra layer of protection not to get the scam ad in the first place.

Privacy tools and settings that limit ad personalization have been available for quite a while. If people who use them were buying worse stuff, the surveillance industry would have said so by now. Anyway, if you’re in the UK, go do the Meta opt-out.

In other countries, other effective privacy tips are still a win.

23 Mar 2025

power moves, signaling, and a helpful book for understanding Big Tech

I’m still waiting for my copy of Careless People by Sarah Wynn-Williams, so I don’t have anything more on the content of the book than what I have seen in other reviews. The local bookstore had a stack—more than they normally order for new hardcovers—but I hesitated and they were gone next time I went in there. So yes, I am a little behind on this.

But come on, people.

Careless People is a best-seller because Meta decision-makers want it to be a best-seller.

In other Big Tech news, Google is delivering ads for obvious malware, with a landing page featuring an unauthorized copy of one of Google’s own logos. Even worse, they got spotted placing ads on Child Sexual Abuse Material. At first these look like embarrassing self-owns, especially for a company that’s contending for favorable PR in the AI business. Is their AI really that bad at classifying landing pages, extension listings, and the content of sites where their ads appear? The search ad malware thing is particularly egregious—the whole point of the deceptive ads that are all over Google Search now is to impersonate some well-known company. It should be a high school level coding project to filter out some of these.

But Big Tech’s apparent eagerness to appear in bad news makes sense when you look at the results. Out of all the people who read and were outraged by Careless People over the weekend, how many are going to come in to work on Monday and delete their Meta tracking pixel or turn off Meta CAPI? And how many people concerned about Google’s malware, CSAM, and infringing content problems are going to switch to inclusion lists and validated SupplyChain objects and stop with the crappy, often illegal ad placements that Google recommends and legit ad agencies don’t? For Big Tech, doing crimes in an obvious way is a power move, a credible, costly signal. If there were a Meta alternative that didn’t do genocide, or an honest alternative to Google search advertising, then advertising decision-makers would have switched to them already. All these embarrassing-looking stories are a signal: don’t waste your time looking for an alternative to paying us. The publisher’s page for Careless People has a Meta pixel on it.

I do have a book recommendation that might be a little easier to get a hold of. Codes of the Underworld by Diego Gambetta was the weekly book recommendation on A Collection of Unmitigated Pedantry. I’m glad to see that it is still in print, because it’s a useful way to help understand the Big Tech companies. Actions that might not have made sense in a company’s old create more value than you capture days are likely to be easier to figure out after understanding the considerations applied by other criminal organizations.

Codes of the Underworld by Diego Gambetta

Criminals have hard-to-satisfy communications needs, such as the need to convey a credible threat to a victim without attracting the attention of enforcers. This is related to the signaling problem faced by honest advertisers, but in reverse. How can a representative of a protection racket indicate to a small business that they represent a true threat, and aren’t just bluffing? Gambetta digs into a variety of signaling problems. It’s a 2009 book, so many of the Big Tech firms were still legit when it came out, but a lot of the communications methods from back then apply to the companies of today.

Is there a solution? As Gambetta points out, real-life organized crime perpetrators tend to copy from the movies, and today they’re copying the partnership with a friendly government subplot from The Godfather Part II. Maybe it’s time to watch that movie again.

15 Mar 2025

privacy laws for slacker states

It has come to my attention that there are still 15 or so states in the USA without privacy laws. This is understandable. We all have a lot of stuff to deal with. And of course there’s the problem of privacy law compliance turning into a time-suck for small businesses. The more that the laws and regulations pile up, the harder to pick out everything you need to do from all those damn PDFs. And it’s not just small companies. Honda just got around to dealing with some obvious differences between GDPR compliance and CCPA compliance that I pointed out back in 2020. And that’s an old PDF and a big company.

But the good news for slacker states is that doing the most work, cranking out the most lines of code, or the most pages of PDFs, or whatever, does not necessarily produce the best results. Given the amount of work that other states, and juridictions like the European Union, have already done on privacy, a slacker state can, right now, get not just the best privacy protection but also save a lot of time and grief for state employees and for business people in your state.

You need two laws. And we know that people are going to print them out, so please keep them short. (Maybe do a printer ink right to refill law next year?)

First, surveillance licenses for Big Tech. This gets you a few benefits.

  • Focus on the riskiest companies with the most money and staff for compliance—don’t put extra work on small local businesses.

  • Save your state’s attorney general and their staff a bunch of time. They’re not Big Tech’s support department. If a Big Tech company drops the ball on user support, just suspend their surveillance license until they clean up their act, like a problem bar and their liquor license.

  • You can define surveillance really briefly in the law and make the big out-of-state companies do the work of describing their surveillance practices in their license application.

That one is pretty easy to do as long as you focus purely on inbound data, the surveillance part, and don’t touch anything that sounds like speech from the company to others. And you can push most of the work off onto Big Tech and a new surveillance licensing board. I’m sure every state has people who would be willing to get on one of those.

Second, copy all the details from other states and countries. The other law would be focused on maximum privacy, minimum effort. The goal is to make a law that small business people can comply with, without even reading it, because they already had to do some privacy thing for somewhere else. Two parts.

  • Any privacy feature offered in some other jurisdiction must be offered here, too. A company only breaks the law if someone out-of-state gets a privacy feature that someone in-state doesn’t.

  • This law may be enforced by anyone except a state employee. (Borrow the Texas S.B. 8 legal hack, to protect yourself from Big Tech industry groups trying to block the law by starting an expensive case.)

A small business that operates purely locally can just do their thing. But if they already have some your California privacy rights feature or whatever, they just turn it on for this state too. Easier compliance project for the companies, better privacy for the users, no enforcement effort for the state, it’s a win-win-win. After all, state legislators don’t get paid by the page, and we each only get one set of carpal tunnels.

14 Mar 2025

Links for 14 March 2025: autonomous drones in the news

How Ukraine integrates machine vision in battlefield drones by Oleksandr Matviienko, Bohdan Miroshnychenko & Zoriana Semenovych. In November 2024, the government procured 3,000 FPV drones with machine vision and targeting technologies. Reports also suggested that the procurement would be expanded to 10,000 units.

Preparing for the next European war by Azeem Azhar. One challenge will be the simple rate of innovation in the actual battlefield. Drone warfare in Ukraine has shown iteration cycles measuring weeks not years. So any systems procured today need to be future-proofed for those dynamics.

Thread by Trent Telenko The logistical facts are that the FM-MAG machine gun, the 60 mm & 81mm mortars, LAWS, Javelins, any infantry crew served weapon you care to name are all going to be most to fully replaced with drones and drone operators, because of the logistical leverage drones represent on the battlefield.

Long-range drone strikes weakening Russia’s combat ability, senior Ukrainian commander says by Deborah Haynes. Some of the drones are remotely piloted, others work via autopilot. Russia’s war has forced Ukraine to use technology and innovation to fight back against its far more powerful foe. It has accelerated the use of autonomous machines in an irreversible transformation of the warzone that everyone is watching and learning from. Brigadier Shchygol said: Right now, Ukraine’s battlefield experience is essentially a manual for the world.

Ukraine Drives Next Gen Robotic Warfare by Mick Ryan. Another more interesting trend has arisen which will force policy makers and military strategists to undertake an even more careful analysis of Ukraine war trends, and how these trends apply in other theatres, particularly the Pacific. This trend, robotic teaming, has emerged over the past year with the advent on drone-on-drone combat in the air and on the ground. In particular, several recent combat actions in Ukraine provide insights that need to be studied and translated for their employment in the massive ocean expanses, tens of thousands of kilometres of littoral, thousands of large and small islands and at least three continents that constitute the Pacific theatre.

DEEP DIVE: Taiwan miltech aims to undermine Chinese components by Tim Mak. Taiwan has learnt the central tech lesson from the war in Ukraine: the next global conflicts will heavily feature cheap, small drones—and in large numbers. So as an electronics and hardware component giant—especially relative to its size and diplomatic status—it is trying not only to develop a domestic industry, but also become an arsenal for the free world, building drones and devices for allied militaries worldwide.

Why America fell behind in drones, and how to catch up again by Cat Orman and Jason Lu. Also Building Drones for Developers: A uniquely open architecture on the F-11 means that every part of the drone is truly built around the [NVIDIAn] Orin [GPU]. This enables sophisticated autonomy applications in which ML models are able to not only analyze data obtained in-flight, but actually use that analysis to inform flight actions in real time.

09 Mar 2025

Pro tips: links for 9 March 2025

Jason Lefkowitz cövers höw to set up the Cømpose key (and make everything you type awesöme™), in Make special characters stupid easy: meet the compose key

switching.software offers Ethical, easy-to-use and privacy-conscious alternatives to well-known software

Pro tip: avoid generative AI images in blog posts (even if your CMS says you should have one for SEO purposes) unless you want to make a political statement: AI: The New Aesthetics of Fascism by Gareth Watkins

Got third-party tracking scripts or pixels on your site? Avoid legal grief, take them off. Caught with Their Hand in the Cookie Jar: CNN’s Privacy Lawsuit is Served Fresh and the Court is Taking a Bite by Blake Landis. (Highest priority is to get rid of the Meta pixel. That’s not just a pro-evil-dictator tattoo for your web site, it’s really easy for lawyers to check for.)

Add data poisoning for AI scrapers hitting your GitHub Pages site: Trapping AI from the Algorithmic Sabotage Research Group (ASRG)

Got a small business? Like riding bikes? Relocating to the Netherlands with DAFT

If you need an integer and all you have is four 2s, Eli Bendersky has some math advice: Making any integer with four 2s

Nearly a Year Later, Mozilla is Still Promoting OneRep (Part of the Mozilla Monitor Plus service. Protip: check Have I Been Pwned directly)

Why you need a radio (yes, you!) by Audrey Eschright

The Linux kernel project can’t use code from sanctioned countries. Other projects need to check compliance with sanctions, too. US Blocks Open Source ‘Help’ From These Countries by Steven J. Vaughan-Nichols

Jake Archibald covers The case against self-closing tags in HTML (you don’t need <br /> just <br>.

John D. Cook makes rounding numbers much easier (if you use balanced ternary) in A magical land where rounding equals truncation

Understanding the legal issues for small community sites under UK law: #2: Five things you need if you run a small, low-risk user-to-user service by Rachel Coldicutt

08 Mar 2025

advertising personalization: good for you?

A new paper is out, collecting some of the top arguments in favor of personalized advertising: The Intended and Unintended Consequences of Privacy Regulation for Consumer Marketing by Jean-Pierre Dubé, John G. Lynch, Dirk Bergemann, Mert Demirer, Avi Goldfarb, Garrett Johnson, Anja Lambrecht, Tesary Lin, Anna Tuchman, Catherine E. Tucker It’s probably going to get cited this privacy law season. But, as an Internet optimist, I’m still not buying the argument that personalized advertising has important benefits that need to be balanced with privacy. Looking at the literature, it is more likely that certain risks are inherent to personalization as such and that reducing personalization is more likely to be a bonus benefit of privacy protection than a trade-off.

Some notes and links follow.

p. 3 We do not consider legal arguments for consumer privacy as a fundamental right or concerns about access to personal data by malign actors or governments.

Avoiding malign actors is the big reason for restricting personalized ads. And malign actors are numerous. The high-profile national security threats are already in the news, but most people will encounter miscellaneous malware, scams, rip-offs and other lesser villainy enabled by ad personalization more often than they have to deal with state or quasi-state adversaries. There is no hard line between malign actors and totally legit sellers—not only does the personalized ad business have plenty of halfway crooks, you can find n/m-way crooks for arbitrary values of n and m.

Ad personalization gives a bunch of hard-to-overcome advantages to deceptive sellers. Although scams are generally illegal and/or against advertising platform policies, personalization makes the rules easier to evade, as we see with some ways that Facebook ads are optimized for deceptive advertising. Most personalized ads aren’t clustered at the good (high-quality pair of shoes in your size, on sale, next door!) or bad (malware pre-configured for your system) ends of the spectrum. Advertisers at all levels of quality and honesty are present, so any framework for thinking about ad personalization needs to take that variability into account.

p. 3 Some privacy advocates assume, incorrectly, that personalized marketing based on granular consumer data is automatically harmful…

Treating personalized advertising as harmful by default is not an assumption, but a useful heuristic based on both theoretical models and real-world experience. personally, I don’t pay attention to your ad if it’s personalized to me—it’s as credible as a cold call. But I might pay attention to your ad if it’s run in a place where the editors of sites that cover your industry would see it, or your mom would. Yes, it is possible for professors to imagine a hypothetical world in which personalization is beneficial, but that only works if you make the unrealistic simplifying assumption that all sellers are honest and that the only impact of personalization is to show people ads that are more or less well matched to them. The theoretical arguments in favor of personalized advertising break down as soon as you level up your economic model to consider the presence of both honest and deceptive advertisers in a market.

See Gardete and Bart, Tailored Cheap Talk: The Effects of Privacy Policy On Ad Content and Market Outcomes. Our research suggests that another peril of sharing very high quality targeting information with advertisers is that ad content may become less credible and persuasive to consumers. An advertising medium that allows for personalization is incapable of conveying as much information from an honest seller to a potential buyer as an advertising medium that does not support personalization.

Mustri et al., in Behavioral Advertising and Consumer Welfare, find that products found in behaviorally targeted ads are likely to be associated with lower quality vendors and higher product prices compared to competing alternatives found among search results.

p. 8 Which Consumers Care Most About Privacy, and Do Privacy Policies Unintentionally Favor the Privileged?

Lots of studies show that, basically, some people really want cross-context personalized advertising, some people don’t, and for the largest group in the middle, it depends how you ask. (references at the 30-40-30 rule). But the difference in consumer preferences is not about privilege, it’s about information level. See Turow et. al, Americans Reject Tailored Advertising and Three Activities That Enable It. That study includes a survey of privacy preferences before and after informing the participants about data practices—and people were more likely to say they do not want tailored advertising after getting the additional information.

In the Censuswide study Who’s In the Know: The Privacy Pulse Report, the experienced advertisers surveyed in the USA (people with 5 or more years of ad experience) were more likely than average to use an ad blocker (66% > 52%), and privacy is now the number one reason for people to use one. It is reasonable for policy-makers to consider the preferences of better-informed people—which is already a thing in fields such as transportation safety and public health.

p. 11 Poorer consumers live in data deserts (Tucker 2023), causing algorithmic exclusion due to missing or fragmented data. This exclusion thwarts marketing outreach and may deprive them of offers, exacerbating data deserts and marginalization.

Instead of speculating about this problem, personalized advertising proponents who are concerned about some people not being tracked enough can already look at other good examples of possibly under-surveilled consumers. Early adopters of privacy tools and preferences are helpfully acting as the experimental group for a study that the surveillance business hasn’t yet run. If people on whom less data is collected are getting fewer win-win offers, then the privacy early adopters should have worse consumer outcomes than people who leave the personalization turned on. For example, Apple iOS users with App Tracking Transparency (ATT) set to allow tracking should be reporting higher satisfaction and doing fewer returns and chargebacks. So far, this does not seem to be happening. (For a related result, see Bian et al., Consumer Surveillance and Financial Fraud. Consumers who deliberately placed themselves in a data desert by changing ATT to disallow tracking reported less fraud.) Click this to buy better stuff and be happier

And there’s little evidence to suggest that if a personalized ad system knows someone to be poor, that they’ll receive more of the kind of legit, well-matched offers that are targeted to the more affluent. Poor people tend to receive more predatory finance and other deceptive offers, so may be better off on average with ads less well matched to their situation.

p. 13 More broadly, without cross-site/app identity, consumers enjoy less free content

This depends on how you measure content and how you define enjoy. The Kircher and Foerderer paper states that, although children’s games for Android got fewer updates on average after a targeted advertising policy change by Google,

Only exceptionally well-rated and demanded games experienced more feature updates, which could be interpreted as a sign of opportunity due to better monetization potential or weakened competition. However, considering that we observed these effects only for games in the highest decile of app quality and demand and given that the median user rating of a game is 4.1 of 5, our findings suggest widespread game abandonment.

By Sturgeon’s Law, a policy change that benefits the top 10% of games but not the bottom 90% (which, in total, account for a small fraction of total installs and an even smaller fraction of gameplay) is a win for the users.

Another relevant paper is Kox, H., Straathof, B., and Zwart, G. (2014). Targeted advertising, platform competition and privacy.

We find that more targeting increases competition and reduces the websites’ profits, but yet in equilibrium websites choose maximum targeting as they cannot credibly commit to low targeting. A privacy protection policy can be beneficial for both consumers and websites.

When both personalized and non-personalized ad impressions are available in the same market, the personalized impressions tend to go for about double the non-personalized. But it doesn’t work to artificially turn off some data collection for a fraction of ad impressions, observe that revenue for those impressions is lower (compared to impressions with the data that are still available), and then extrapolate the revenue difference to a market in which no impressions have the data available.

It is also important to consider the impact of extremely low-quality and/or illegal content in the personalized advertising market. Much of the economic role of ad personalization is not to match the right ad to the right user but to monetize a higher-value user on lower-value content. The surveillance economy is more like the commodification economy. Surveillance advertising companies are willing to pursue content commodification even to the point of taking big reputational risks from feeding ad money to the worst people on the Internet (Hiding in Plain Sight: The Ad-Supported Piracy Ring Driving Over a Billion Monthly Visits - deepsee.io, Senators Decry Adtech Failures as Ads Appear On CSAM Site). If advertising intermediaries were more limited in their ability to put a good ad on a bad site using user tracking, the higher-quality content sites would enjoy significantly increased market power.

p. 14 Restrictions to limit the effectiveness of digital advertising would likely disproportionately disadvantage small businesses, since nine out of ten predominantly use digital advertising, especially on Meta

Are small businesses really better off in the surveillance advertising era? Although personalized Big Tech advertising is the main ad medium available to small businesses today, there is clearly some survivorship bias going on here. The Kerrigan and Keating paper states that, While entrepreneurship has rebounded since the Great Recession and its aftermath, startup activity remains weak by historical standards. This period of time overlaps with the golden age of personalized advertising, after widespread adoption of smartphones but before Apple’s ATT, the EU’s GDPR, and California’s CCPA. If personalized advertising is so good for small businesses, where are the extra small businesses enabled by it? We should have seen a small business boom in the second half of the 2010s, after most people in the USA got smartphones but before CCPA and ATT.

Jakob Nielsen may have provided the best explanation in 2006’s Search Engines as Leeches on the Web, which likely applies not just to search, but to other auction-based ad placements like social media advertising. An auction-based advertising platform like those operated by Google and Meta is able to dynamically adjust its advertising rates to capture all of the expected incremental profits from the customers acquired through it.

Part of the missing small business effect may also be caused by platform concentration. If, instead of an advertising duopoly, small businesses had more options for advertising, the power balance between platform (rentier) and small business (entrepreneur) might shift more toward the latter. See also Crawford et al., The antitrust orthodoxy is blind to real data harms. Policy makers might choose to prioritize pro-competition privacy legislation such as surveillance licensing for the largest, riskiest platforms in order to address competition concerns in parallel with privacy ones.

p. 15 Since PETs are costly for firms to implement, forward-looking regulation should consider how to incentivize PET adoption and innovation further.

In a section about how so-called privacy-enhancing technologies (PETs) have equal perceived privacy violation and bigger competition issues than conventional personalization, why recommend incentivizing PETs? The works cited would better support a recommendation to have a more detailed or informative consent experience for PETs than for cookie-based tracking. Because PETs obfuscate real-world privacy problems such as fraud and algorithmic discrimination, it would be more appropriate to require additional transparency, and possibly licensing, for PETs.

PETs, despite their mathematical appeal to many at Big Tech firms, have a long list of problems when applied to the real world. The creeped-out attitude of users toward PETs is worth paying attention to, as people who grow up in market economies generally develop good instincts about information in markets—just like people who grow up playing ball games can get good at catching a ball without consciously doing calculus. Policymakers should pay more attention to user perceptions—which are based on real-world market activity—than to mathematical claims about developers’ PET projects. PETs should be considered from the point of view of regulators investigating discrimination and fraud complaints, which are often difficult to spot on large platforms. Because PETs have the effect of shredding the evidence of platform misdeeds, enabling the existing problems of adtech, just in a harder-to-observe way, they need more scrutiny, not incentivization.

Coming soon: a useful large-scale experiment

Policymakers may soon be able to learn from what could be the greatest experiment on the impact of ad personalization ever conducted.

If Meta is required to offer Facebook users in the European Union a meaningfully de-personalized ad experience (and not just the less personalized ads option that still allows for personalization using fraud risk factors like age, gender, and location) then there will be a chance to measure what happens when users can choose personalized or de-personalized ads on a service that is otherwise the same.

Personally, I bet that users with the personalization turned off will have better outcomes as consumers, but we’ll see. I’m pretty confident that personalized ads will turn out to be worse because tools and settings that tend to make personalization less effective have been available for a while, and if choosing the privacy option made you buy worse stuff, the surveillance companies would have said so by now.

Conclusion

I put these links and notes together to help myself out when someone drops a link to the Dubé et al. paper into an Internet argument, and put them up here in the hope that they will help others. Hardly anyone will read all the literature in this field, but a lot of the most interesting research is still found in corners of the library that Big Tech isn’t actively calling attention to.

Thanks to Fengyang Lin for reviewing a draft of this post.

02 Mar 2025

two open source stories

First, I know that pretty much everyone is (understandably) freaking out about stuff that is getting worse, but I just wanted to share some good news in the form of an old-fashioned open-source success story. I’m a fairly boring person and developed most of my software habits in the late 1990s and early 2000s, so it’s pretty rare that I actually hit a bug.

But so far this blog has hit two: one browser compatibility issue and this one. The script for rebuilding when a file changes depends on the inotifywait utility, and it turned out that until recently it breaks when you ask it to watch more than 1024 files.

  1. I filed a bug

  2. A helpful developer, Jan Kratochvil, wrote a fix and put in a pull request.

  3. A bot made test packages and commented with instructions for me on how to test the fix.

  4. I commented that the new version works for me

  5. The fix just went into Fedora. Pretty damn slick.

This is a great improvement over how this kind of thing used to work. I hardly had to do anything. These kids today don’t know how good they have it.

story number 2: why support the Linux desktop?

Amazon Chime is shutting down. Did anyone use it? I get invited to a lot of video conferences, and I never got invited to an Amazon Chime meeting. Even though Amazon.com is normally really good at SaaS, this one didn’t take off. What happened?

It looks like Amazon Chime was an interesting example of Nassim Nicholas Taleb’s intransigent minority effect.

The system requirements for Amazon Chime look pretty reasonable, right? Should get 95% of the client systems out there. The number of desktop Linux users is pretty small. But if you have 20 meetings a week, at 95% compatibility you’re going to average a compatibility issue every week. Even worse, the people you most want to make a good first impression on are the people whose client platform you’re least likely to know.

And if you do IT support for a company with 100 people organizing meetings, Amazon Chime is going to cause way too many support issues to put up with. Taleb uses the examples of kosher and halal food—only a small fraction of the population will only eat kosher or halal, but when planning food for a large group, the most practical choice is to satisfy the minority.

The minority rule will show us how it all it takes is a small number of intolerant virtuous people with skin in the game, in the form of courage, for society to function properly.

Anyway, something to keep in mind in the future for anyone considering moving the support desktop Linux or support Firefox tickets to backlog. None of the successul video conferencing platforms give me any grief for my Linux/Firefox/privacy nerdery client-side setup.